Ideal Money
The special commodity or medium that we call money has a long
and interesting history. And since we are so dependent on our use of it and so
much controlled and motivated by the wish to have more of it or not to lose
what we have we may become irrational in thinking about it and fail to be
able to reason about it
like about a technology, such as radio, to be used more or less efficiently.
So I wish to present the argument that various interests and
groups, notably including "Keynesian" economists, have sold to the public a
"quasi-doctrine" which
teaches, in effect, that "less is more" or that (in other words)
"bad money is better than good money". Here we can remember the
classic ancient economics
saying called "Gresham's law" which was "The bad money drives
out the good". The saying of Gresham's is mostly of interest
here because it
illustrates the "old" or "classical" concept of "bad
money" which concept is not according to the thinking of this variety of
economists.
Money, Utility, and Game Theory
In the sort of game theory that is studied and applied by
economists
the concept of
"utility" is very fundamental and essential. Von Neumann and
Morgenstern give a notably good and thorough treatment of utility in their book
(on game theory and economic behavior). The concept of utility (mathematical)
does indeed predate the book of Von Neumann and Morgenstern. And for example,
as a concept, mathematical utility can be traced back to
a paper published in 1886
in Pisa by G. B. Antonelli.
When one studies what are called "cooperative games",
which in economic terms include mergers and acquisitions or cartel formation,
it is found to
be appropriate and is
standard to form two basic classifications:
(1): Games with transferable utility.
(and)
(2): Games without transferable utility
(or "NTU" games).
In the world of practical realities it is money which typically
causes
the existence of a game of
type (1) rather than of type (2); money is the lubrication" which enables
the efficient "transfer of utility". And generally if games can be
transformed from type (2) to type (1) there is a gain, on average, to all the
players in terms of whatever might be expected to be the outcome.
But this function of money in generally facilitating the
transfer of utility would seem to be as well performed by the currency of
Thailand as by that of Switzerland. Or the question can be asked "How do
'good money' and
'bad money' differ, if at
all, for the valuable function of facilitating utility transfer?". But if
we consider contracts having a relatively long
time axis then the
difference can be seen clearly.
Consider a society where the money in use is subject to a rapid
and unpredictable rate of inflation so that money worth 100 now might be worth
from 50 to 10 by a year from now. Who would want to lend money for the term
of a year?
In this context we can see how the "quality" of a
money standard can strongly influence areas of the economy involving financing
with longer-term credits.
"Keynesians"
The thinking of J. M. Keynes was actually multi-dimensional and
consequently there are quite different varieties of persons at the present time
who follow, in one way or another, some of the thinking of Keynes.
And of course SOME of his
thinking was scientifically accurate and thus not disputable. For example, an
early book written by Keynes was the mathematical text "A Treatise on
Probability".
The label "Keynesian" is convenient, but to be safe
we should have a defined meaning for this as a party that can be criticized and
contrasted
with other parties.
So let us define "Keynesian" to be descriptive of a
"school of thought" that originated at the time of the devaluations
of the pound and the dollar
in the early 30's of the
20th century. Then, more specifically, a "Keynesian" would favor the
existence of a "manipulative" state establishment of central bank and
treasury which would continuously seek to achieve "economic welfare"
objectives with comparatively little regard for the long term reputation of the
national currency and the associated effects of that on the reputation
of financial enterprises
domestic to the state.
And indeed a very famous saying of Keynes was "... in the
long run we
will all be dead
...".
Historical Observations
{Originally, these remarks were mostly made with the aid of a
blackboard (or some sort of a board for writing display).}
The history of the "gold standard" is rather
interesting. It can be
traced back to 1717 when
Isaac Newton, as "Master of the Mint" in London,
set a standard quantum of
gold to correspond to the currency called the "'pound' sterling". And
in 1931 this standard finally failed to be supported any longer, and that was
at a time when the London government had shifted
to the left politically
and a time also of global economic stresses.
The US dollar had itself been imitatively put on a fixed
relation to
gold, like various other
currencies at various times. That relation was not supported after 1933,
similarly to the case of the British pound. And another similarly linked currency
was the Swiss franc. In its case the original standard relation to gold was
discontinued in 1936.
And in later times, viewed retrospectively, it could be said
that there were times and places where it perhaps SEEMED as if there were a
"gold standard" but that there really wasn't that. In 1971 there
came, under the presidency of Nixon in Washington, the final complete disavowal
of the
concept of a linkage
between the US dollar and gold. This was naturally also the beginning of a
period of strong inflation in terms of dollar prices.
Central Banks as "Pardoners" and
as Printers of Money
A debt-pardoner is an agency or authority that can pardon the
"sins" of the over-indebted or of those who otherwise would go
bankrupt. Banks can thus sometimes be saved from failing. The government, of a
country where it issues the locally accepted currency, also thus pardons its
own "sins".
If the "euro" currency becomes established then Rome
and Paris will no longer be able to play the same ro^les as
"pardoners" as they have in the past. National "pardoners"
will become ineffective, within the area of the "euro", unless they
secede from the eurocurrency bloc. Instead pardoning will depend on the actions
of a sort of "Holy Roman Emperor" in Frankfurt, which would be able
to pardon ensemble all the debt-sinners of the euromoney bloc.
The British and the "Euro"
The inhabitants of the UK, having in the past had the best and
most dominant of all currencies, as well as the biggest colonial
"empire", may
feel so much reluctant to
accept the "come down" that agreeing to the rule
of a (collective) Holy
Roman Emperor in Frankfurt would entail that they will decline to accept
membership in the euromoney bloc.
Technically, it would be possible for them to arrange to have
a money
of their own that would be
of quality not less than that of the "euro". (Presumably this would
be the Swiss strategy.)
Ideal Money
So the euro-money prospect opens up many interesting
potentialities of games of alignment. In general, membership in a "social
club" is desirable only if there are non-members. A good alliance can be reduced
to an absurdity by becoming too broadly inclusive. But a global money standard
could have a value similar to that of standard measures such as those of the
"metric system".
There is a tremendous value in simply having prices quoted
conveniently. With an euro-money standard a manufacturer in Spain can give
information simply to prospective customers in France or Germany. That would be
comparable to conditions in the USA where items can be ordered from catalogs
and
shipped interstate with
only the complication of the state retail sales
taxes sometimes being
involved.
States Without Sin
(This was originally presented in "blackboard
display" format, rather
than in verbal lecture
style.)
It was observed that the states listed: Luxembourg, Andorra, Liechtenstein, San
Marino, Monaco, and the Vatican City; have been constitutionally without
"sin", in the sense of the defaulting of bankrupts, and they have
also not themselves "pardoned" any money debtors. This is simply
because they have not printed any money for which they would also determine the
value. Each of these would either issue a currency with value defined by the
value of the currency issued by some larger state or simply not issue any
currency.
And outside of Europe there are Panama and Liberia which can be
named as examples of the same category.
Economics and Money Quality
How does the traditional quality of a state's currency
correlate with
the typical level of
economic advancement and the "standard of living"? The correlation
seems to be positive since Switzerland has a notably high standard of
prosperity and notably "good" money, and of course the whole spectrum
of prosperity and money
quality of states must be studied for a scientific conclusion.
How Could "Good Money" Become a Standard?
The historical fact seems to be that the "gold
standard" was, in its time, a basis that favored the prosperity of the
U.K. and of other states like the USA and Switzerland that adopted the concept
of the standard. But nowadays
few would propose a return
to the actual use simply of the metal gold
as a standard. Several
factors can be mentioned: (1) The cost of mining
gold effectively does
depend on the technology. Recent cyanide leaching
techniques have made it
again possible to profitably mine gold at formerly abandoned sites in the USA
so that the USA is now a big producer. But the unpredictability of the cost is
a negative factor. (2) The location of potential gold mining places may not be
"politically appealing" so that
it would seem undesirable
to make a political choice to enhance the economic importance of those
particular areas. (3) There is some negative psychology about gold so that even
if it were the most logical choice, after all, still the unpopularity of the
idea could be very obstructive. And (4) It can be recognized as wasteful of labor
if gold is accumulated much beyond its
various uses and put into
storage vaults like in Fort Knox in the USA.
But a modern alternative is possible, one that would provide a
good standard independent of state pardoners". This idea occurred to me comparatively
recently.
But the possibilities with regard to actually establishing a
norm of money systems which could qualify as of "ideal" type are
dependent on the political circumstances of the world. If the world had in fact
become a single empire with a central government for the whole world then what
is now international trade, with shipping on the oceans through areas
considered to be the property of no state, would be replaced by the equivalent
of domestic commerce within the USA.
And this would profoundly modify the circumstances relevant to
the establishing of "good" or "bad" systems of money. What
I have to suggest is not viewed as appropriate for the world empire context.
It can also be remarked that "bad" money, or the
inverse of "good" or "ideal" money is basically a
consequence of deficiencies on the part of governments and politicians of a
sort relating to morals, virtue, or ethics. Thus the phenomena of "bad
money" are essentially understandable via Machiavellian studies.
We of Terra could be taught how to have ideal monetary systems
if wise
and benevolent
extra-terrestrials were to "take us in hand" and administer
our national money systems
analogously to how the currency of Hong Kong was administered during the later
years of British Hong Kong.
Natural Comparisons of Value
In most states having an "advanced economy" there are
statistics prepared by the authorities that are comparable to the U.S.
"consumer price index".
(In the U.S. this
statistic goes back to times when the dollar was indeed
a gold standard currency.)
As inflation has become more of a standard and expected phenomenon the CPI has
been used and interpreted as the most realistic and practical measure of the
actual rate of the inflation. When it is at the 2% or 3% level it is currently
fashionable for all economic and financial commentators to say that
"inflation is not a problem" or "inflation is under
control". This of course involves a sort of psychology. Over the current
expected human lifetime of 70 years one unit of currency of the value at the
time of a person's birth would be worth more than 4 units of it of the value at
the time of that person's expiration.
A Non-Political Value Standard
A possible non-political basis for a value standard which could
be used for money would be a good "ICPI" statistic where this acronym
refers to "industrial consumption price index". That could be
calculated from the international prices of commodities, such as copper,
silver, tungsten, etc. that are used in industrial activities.
Here we can return to the understanding that money has the
practical
value of creating games
for traders that are games with transferable utility when without the money
being available the game of the traders would be
a game without
transferable utility and thus naturally a game with less efficiency in relation
to the possibilities for the participants of maximizing their combined
situation of gains.
And then if we consider which commodities would be optimally
suitable to provide a basis for a means of transferring utility then, if we
specifically consider the possibility that the trading partners may be located
in different nations and perhaps on different continents then the suitability
of such commodities, in relation to the ideal function of facilitating utility
transfer, depends on the extent such a commodity can seem to have a value
independent of its geographical location.
Clearly, in terms of this geographical perspective, gold has
been historically optimal and that largely because the labor cost of moving it
over great distances is so small in relation to the value of what is
transported.
Thus it formed a very
efficiently movable medium for the transportation
of a value exchangeable
for other values ultimately deriving, in one way or another, from human labor
(with the achievements of warriors here also viewed as involving labor). But
right now platinum would be even better than gold because of having more value
per unit of weight.
Crude petroleum could also be used for barter transactions, and
in relation to the present state of the global economy it would seem a proper
component of an index of prices of internationally traded commodities that
enter into the costs of industrial consumption. We can see that times could
change, especially if a "miracle energy source" were found, and thus
if a good ICPI index is constructed it should not be expected to be valid, as
initially defined, into all eternity. It would instead be appropriate for it to
be regularly readjusted depending on how the patterns of international trade
would actually evolve. Here, evidently, politicians in control of the authority
behind standards COULD corrupt the continuity of a good standard, but depending
on how things were fundamentally arranged, the probabilities
of serious damage through
"political corruption" might become as small as
the probabilities that the
values of the standard meter and kilogram will be corrupted through the actions
of politicians.
Also, commodities with easily and reliably calculable prices
are most suitable, and relatively stable prices are very desirable.
Another basic cost that could be used would be a standard
transportation cost, the cost of shipping a unit quantity of something over
long international distances.
So it seems that such an ICPI index could be calculated in an
essentially "scientific" fashion, after some practical initial
choices were made. And this standard, as a basis for the standardization of the
value of the international money unit, would remove, where it would be used,
the political ro^les of
the "grand
pardoners", the state authorities that can forgive the debts of
debtors including,
particularly, those of themselves. (The "national debt"
of a state can, in
principle, be "trivialized" by a sufficient amount of inflation.)
Euro, Frankfurt, Standard
If such an objective and non-political standard were used in
the
Frankfurt of a euro-money
system then there would not be an "Holy Roman Emperor" (although of a
collective structure) with the power to pardon or
not to pardon the
debt-sins of all European debtors (of the zone) in general.
So there would be nothing
to argue about, such as whether or not those most desirous of Keynesian
"pardoning" should be favored with a general pardoning
of past debts by the fiat
of inflation.
Refined Indices
If the technical problem of designing an index of prices to
serve as a basis for a money of standard value is considered in a more elaborate
fashion it seems that there is the possibility of defining the sort of index
which would vary "smoothly" and yet would also vary in an appropriate
way over longer periods of time. Here the apparent problem is that the prices
of certain commodities which would be ideally suited to measure long term
changes in the costs of industrial production may tend naturally to be
"volatile"
in their variations
depending on business cycles. And the prices of other commodities or services,
etc. might tend to vary much more gradually or smoothly but not be reliable in
terms of long term considerations for one
or another reason.
For example, the prices of copper and nickel might very well
represent, over long time periods, the actual costs of industrial production,
while
the prices of silver and
gold might tend to vary, comparatively, much more "smoothly" than
those of the baser metals. It is possible to construct a
price index, based on
"moving averages", that would have the smoothness of
the prices of the gold and
silver and yet, over longer time periods, would basically follow the values of
the baser metals. This could be done by computing a "moving average"
of the base metals index computed by pricing
them modulo the index of
the precious metals.
In actual application it would not be a matter of
"base" and precious metals but rather of a variety of commodities
that would be selected for
their suitability in one
sense or the other. And in the index formed from things with naturally
"smoothly varying" prices it seems that it would be intrinsically
quite feasible to make use of costs of services, or energy,
or prices that depend on
the national location of the definition of the commodity, service, or asset
being priced.
So by using this approach the temptation to include things that
would otherwise seem inappropriate just to obtain stability or smoothness can
be avoided.
And of course the fundamental principle remains that if a
political basis existed for changes in a standard index that it is not unlikely
that a form
of "corruption"
would appear. This is comparable to the issue that was raised recently in the
USA where certain interests wished to devalue the original
CPI computed by the Labor
Department so as to have more federal budget money available to reduce taxes or
for other purposes with Social Security beneficiaries being given less.
Practical Considerations on Long Term Value
Trends And the Safe Deposit Box Singularity
There is a problem for the issuer of a currency, whether in
coinage, paper, or "electronic" form, that if this currency (or
money) is TOO GOOD
then it could be exploited
by all sorts of parties and interests that might simply wish to safely deposit
a store of wealth or even to conservatively invest some assets for future good
value. (The word good is used here in terms of comparative value trends, like
in "good investments".) Then under extreme conditions the currency
issued by one state could be exploited by parties not of that state as a sort
of "safe deposit box" on which they would not need to pay any rental
fees or pay any fees like those paid to the managers of mutual funds for
investment.
But simply to improve the conditions under which agreements for
long term lending and borrowing would be made a money would be more or less
equivalently good if it had a completely steady and constant rate of inflation.
Then this inflation rate could be added to all lending and borrowing contracts.
So the problem of a money that would be "TOO GOOD" is thus avoidable.
However, this is not known as a problem in the past history of
money.
And in fact there is a
natural character of the sort of material things
to which money standards
have been related that makes them naturally tend
not to provide "too
good" a channel for investment. It has simply not been profitable, in the
past, for any economic parties to use any variety of money as a channel for
investment, although of course there has been much "currency
speculation" which is a different thing.
Of course also the issuer of a currency needs to be properly
prepared for the possibility of speculation on the part of interests domiciled
in foreign states, etc., etc.
Natural Value Trends
The long term trend of the value of any index of prices will
depend, sometimes predictably, on the choice of the composition of that index.
It is
a coincidental fact that
the inherent nature of mining and mining technology makes it possible for the
prices of certain commodities that are produced
as a result of the
devotion of labor and capital to the effort of mining to increase less (or
decrease more) than might be expected. There is a "dimension
paradox": agricultural products are produced by using the 2-dimensional
resource of the earth's surface, so the "disappearing frontier"
creates a limitation. But in contrast some mining, particularly for elemental
metals,
is essentially able to
operate in 3 dimensions, although of course there are increasing costs for deep
digging. So really there is lots and lots of gold, silver, platinum, tungsten,
etc. out there and more can be found by digging deeper.
Thus an index can be so chosen that its value does not rise
like that, say, of a "typical Rembrandt" or like the ratio of the
human population to
the total surface area of
the Earth. If the value trend of a currency is such that a natural interest
rate is not negative then it is not an unattractive task for a central currency
authority to mint or print the physical currency that would circulate. Then the
issuer of currency would be partially in the position of a borrower not paying
interest on borrowed money.
Opening for Questions or Debate
%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%%
(The above text originally derives from my outline for the
lectures given at various specific locations of the "European School of
Economics" in Italy during October 1997. Subsequent to that time, after
consulting with some of the economics faculty at Princeton, I learned of the
work and publications of Friedrich von Hayek. I must say that my thinking is
apparently quite parallel to his thinking in relation to money and particularly
with regard to the non-typical viewpoint in relation to the functions of the
authorities which in recent times have been the sources of currencies (earlier
"coinage").)
(There have been some later revisions and expansions of the
text and I subsequently also spoke on this topic at Northwestern, at Yale, in
Athens, Greece, and at a meeting in Tampa, Florida, USA. And then my lecture
there
was published in the SEJ
journal.)