Ideal Money and Asymptotically
Ideal Money
Revolutionary or Evolutionary Changes
or Reforms of Systems of Money
Our topic is focused on an ideal, specifically
on “Ideal Money”, and it is not hard to see that there are naturally different
routes by which a system of money might become either improved or might become,
in some senses, more degraded and less worthy of praise. Change can come at a
stroke, like when Alexander cut the Gordian knot, or it can come in a gradual
fashion, through many smaller steps, and this latter can be classed as the
pathway of “evolutionary change”.
It is easy
to illustrate cases of “revolutionary” reform or change in systems of money. A
good example came in 1717 when Isaac Newton, supported by George II, fixed the
value of the local UK currency to a precise amount of gold that defined the
value of the currency (the “pound”) in such a way that it was immediately
recognizable throughout the Continent (of Europe) as of a fixed value
in relation to generally accepted standards (of the
time). (And this was the origin of the “gold standard”.)
Another
example of revolutionary change was when Argentina attempted to establish an
internationally respectable system of money by means of a “currency board”.
(This attempt failed conspicuously, but the failure was rather similar to a
bankruptcy event involving an ordinary commercial bank which simply turned out
to have insuffi-cient “capital”.)
When the
use of paper and printing was developed in China that made possible a
“revolutionary” change, namely the introduction of paper money.
Jacques
Rueff, F. A. von Hayek, and R. Mundell are notable scholars and economists who
have particularly contributed to the theories of how a system or systems of
money might be improved in an effectively revolutionary fashion. For example
there has been a quite dramatic improvement in the (internationally perceived
apparent) quality of the money used in the countries of Italy and Greece simply
because they have moved through the revolu-tionary transition of renouncing the
use of the lira or the drachma and have accepted the use of the newly
established “euro” unit.
Evolutionary Changes and Relevant Teachings
On the
other hand (from the case of “revolutionary” changes) there is often the
possibility that a system of money may gradually improve in quality, either
through somewhat accidental circumstances (like a very favorable trade balance)
or through the learning of good teachings
of applicable varieties.
A series
of American economists have been notable through their contributions which have
enhanced the under-standing of how systems of money actually function and
particularly of how the dollar (US) and its value have been interacting with
the relevant factors of influence. There has always been some “populist”
thinking in the USA which
can encourage ideas about money that are not well
based
in any scientific sense. And the teachings of some
of the notable economists have sometimes given a more scientific perspective on
the areas where the “populist” viewpoints have been influential.
M.
Friedman acquired fame through teaching the linkage between the supply of money
and, effectively, its value.
In retrospect it seems as if elementary, but Friedman
was as if a teacher who re-taught to American economists the classical concept
of the “law of supply and demand”, this in connection with money.
We can
also note at this point that the understanding of the effects of the uncontrolled
behavior of all the various “users” of a domestic money is the inclusive
category of description into which the notable contribut-ions of a series of
American economists can be recognized.
F. Kydland, R. Lucas, E. Phelps, and E. Prescott are notable American
economists who have contributed to the
better understanding of issues arising in the area
of theories of “macroeconomics”. Without arguing for a direct
constitutional reform of the status quo of the
dollar
in the USA they have contributed much enlightenment
in relation to the interactions between intelligent categories
of the “users” of currencies (or in particular the
dollar)
and “the central authorities” (of central bank,
treasury,
state institutions, executive and legislative
government).
The
evolving recognition of the fact that the “users”
of a currency become like players in a game and have
optional strategies by means of which they will be able
to seek to optimize according to their own particular
economic interests leads to the recognition that the tasks
of central planners and managers, of a state, are
not as
simple as if they had only to herd flocks of sheep.
Thus the
“users”, like the managers, can be viewed as
players in interactive games. In particular, with
this
perspective, it is natural to think of the users as
having
“expectations” in relation to the future value of
the
domestic currency, compared either with real assets,
foreign currencies, or indices of costs. These expectations
may or may not be “well-founded” or “rational” but
they
will inevitably guide or influence the choices made
by the “users”.
General Considerations and History
The
special commodity or medium that we call money
has a long and interesting history. And since we are
so dependent on our use of it and so much controlled and motivated by the wish
to have more of it or not to lose what we have we may become irrational in
thinking about
it and fail to be able to reason about it as if
about a technology, such as radio, to be used more or less effici-ently.
We present
the argument that various interests and groups, notably including
"Keynesian" economists, have sold to the public a
"quasi-doctrine" which teaches, in effect, that "less is more"
or that (in other words) "bad money is better than good money". Here
we can remember the classic ancient economics saying called "Gresham's
law" which
was "The bad money drives out the good".
The saying of Gresham's is mostly of interest here because it illustrates
the "old" or "classical" concept
of "bad money" and this can be contrasted with more recent attitudes
which have been very much influenced by the Keynesians and by the results of
their influence on government policies since
the 30's.
Digression on the Philosophy of Money
It seems
to be relevant to the politics of state decisions that affect the character of
currency systems promoted by states that there are typical popular attitudes in
relation to money. Although money itself is merely an artifact of practical
usefulness in human societies and/or civilizations, there are some traditional
or popular views associating money with sin or immorality or unethical or
unjust behavior. And such views can have the effect that
an ideal of good money does not seem such a good
cause
as an ideal of a good public water supply. There is
also,
for example, the Islamic concept which has the
effect
of classing as "usury" any lending of
money at interest. (Here we can wonder about what sort of inflation rates might
have been typical for any major varieties of money, such as Byzantine money, at
the times actually contempor-aneous with the Prophet Mohammed.)
In
general, money has been associated in popular views with moral or ethical
faults, like greed, avarice, selfish-ness, and lack of charity. But on the
other hand, the existence of money often makes it easy to make valuable
donations of philanthropic sorts and the parties receiving such contributions
tend to find it most helpful when the donations are received as money!
But the
New Testament story about "money changers" being driven from the
Temple illustrates clearly the idea of putting the clearly mundane and possibly
"unclean" utility of money at some distance from where that money
would presumably continue to be received when used as
a vehicle for donations.
Economics
has been called "the dismal science" and
it is certainly an area of studies where "the
mundane"
is appropriately studied.
And
philosophically viewed, money exists only because humanity does not live under
"Garden of Eden" conditions and there are specializations of labor
functions. So we
are always exchanging, mediated by money transfers,
the differing fruits of our varied forms of labor.
Welfare Economics
A related
topic, which we can't fully consider in a
few paragraphs, is that of the efforts to be made by
the national state and society in general for dealing with "social
equity" and concerns for the general "economic welfare". Here
the key viewpoint is methodological, as we see it. HOW should society and the
state authorities seek to improve economic welfare generally and what should
be done at times of abnormal economic difficulties
or "depression"?
We can't
go into it all, but we feel that actions which are clearly understandable as
designed for the purpose
of achieving a "social welfare" result are
best. And in particular, programs of unemployment compensation seem to be
comparatively well structured so that they can operate in proportion to the
need. And public works projects
allow the wealthy to pay through taxes to provide
jobs
for workers and these can produce valuable works if
the projects are well planned.
Money,
Utility, and Game Theory
In the
sort of game theory that is studied and applied by economists the concept of
"utility" is very fundamental and essential. Von Neumann and
Morgenstern give a notably good and thorough treatment of utility in their book
(on game theory and economic behavior). The concept of utility (mathematical)
does indeed predate the book of Von Neumann and Morgenstern. And for example,
as a concept, mathemat-ical utility can be traced back to a paper published in
1886 in Pisa by G. B. Antonelli.
When one
studies what are called "cooperative games", which in economic terms
include mergers and acquisitions
or cartel formation, it is found to be appropriate
and
is standard to form two basic classifications:
(1):
Games with transferable utility.
(and)
(2):
Games without transferable utility
(or "NTU" games).
In the
world of practical realities it is money which typically causes the existence
of a game of type (1) rather than of type (2); money is the
"lubrication" which enables the efficient "transfer of
utility". And generally if games can be transformed from type (2) to type
(1) there is a gain, on average, to all the players in terms of whatever might
be expected to be the outcome.
But this
function of money in generally facilitating the transfer of utility would seem
to be as well performed by the currency of Zimbabwe as by that of Switzerland.
Or the question can be asked "How do 'good
money' and
'bad money' differ, if at all, for the valuable
function
of facilitating utility transfer?". But if we
consider contracts having a relatively long time axis then the difference can
be seen clearly.
Consider a
society where the money in use is subject to a rapid and unpredictable rate of
inflation so that money worth 100 now might be worth from 50 to 10 by a year
from now. Who would want to lend money for the term of a year?
In this
context we can see how the "quality" of a money standard can strongly
influence areas of the economy invol-ving financing with longer-term credits.
And also,
if we view money as of importance in connect-ion with transfers of utility, we
can see that money itself is a sort of "utility", using the word in
another sense, comparable to supplies of water, electric energy or tele-communications.
And then, if we think about it, we can consider the quality of money as
comparable to the quality of some "public utility" like the supply of
electric energy or of water.
"Keynesians"
The
thinking of J. M. Keynes was actually multidimen-sional and consequently there
are quite different varieties of persons at the present time who follow, in one
way or another, some of the thinking of Keynes. And of course SOME of his
thinking was scientifically accurate and thus not disputable. For example, an
early book written by Keynes was the mathematical text "A Treatise on
Probability".
The label
"Keynesian" is convenient, but to be safe we should have a defined
meaning for this as a party that can be criticized and contrasted with other
parties.
So let us
define "Keynesian" to be descriptive of a "school of
thought" that originated at the time of the devaluations of the pound and
the dollar in the early 30's of the 20th century. Then, more specifically, a
"Keynesian" would favor the existence of a "manipulative"
state establishment of central bank and treasury which would continuously seek
to achieve "economic welfare" objectives with comparatively little
regard for the long term reput-ation of the national currency and the
associated effects of that on the reputation of financial enterprises domestic
to the state.
And indeed
a very famous saying of Keynes was "...in the long run we will all be dead
...".
A
Critique of the Science of the Keynesians
It is
difficult to make a criticism here because
so much of the scientific research work,
particularly
of American economists, in the years since, say,
"the thirties", has been in the area of the study of the topic called
"macroeconomics" and most or almost all of this work has a
"Keynesian" orientation.
I think
there is a good analogy to mathematical theories like, for example, "class
field theory". In mathematics a set of axioms can be taken as a foundation
and then an area for theoretical study is brought into being. For example, if
one set of axioms is specified and accepted we have the theory of rings while
if another set of axioms is the foundation we have the theory of Moufang loops.
So, from a
critical point of view, the theory of macroeconomics of the Keynesians is like
the theory
of plane geometry without the axiom of Euclid that
was classically called the "parallel postulate". (It is an
interesting fact in the history of science that there was
a time, before the nineteenth century, when
mathematicians were speculating that this axiom or postulate was not necessary,
that it should be derivable from the others.)
So I feel
that the macroeconomics of the Keynesians
is comparable to a scientific study of a
mathematical area which is carried out with an insufficient set of axioms. And the
result is analogous to the situation in plane geometry, the plane does not need
to be really flat and
the area within a circle can expand hyperbolically
as a function of the radius rather than merely with the square of the radius.
(This picture suggests the pattern of
inflation that can result in a country, over
extended
time periods, when there is continually a certain
amount
of gradual inflation.)
The
missing axiom is simply an accepted axiom that
the money being put into circulation by the central
authorities should be so handled as to maintain, over
long terms of time, a stable value.
Instead of
this one can observe, in the context of
the popularity of "Keynesian"
orientations, that it is considered extremely undesirable that there should
ever occur a period of deflation (where wages and prices might be forced to
decrease) but that continual inflation is an acceptable consequence (of
whatever actually causes it under the effective circumstances of the actual
"manage-ment" of a national money system).
Looking
backwards, in the period of time between 1717 and 1931 the Bank of England
actually had to operate with the axiom accepted that we are viewing as
comparable to Euclid's "parallel postulate". The theory of what can
be done, in central banking, with a money value axiom being
in effect is not an empty theory but this is an area
which seems hardly to have been studied at all since the advent of "the
Keynesians" in "the thirties".
Another
aspect of "Keynesianism", in relation to scientific themes, is that
it seems to me to be very much like a school of medical theory and to be
oriented towards "therapeutic" procedures. But often a school of
medical practice can be criticized from one or another point of view. For example,
"What are the long term consequences
of the continued application of the procedures of
therapy?"
The
Machiavellian Perspective
A serious
study of the phenomena of paper money or coinage as issued by state authorities
would not be complete without consideration of a Machiavellian analysis of the
"con games" that arise whenever the quality level
of a money may seem different to different types of
apprai-sers. And Machiavelli is very notable as an early
"non-mathematical" game theorist (!!).
The issuer
of a state-sponsored "legal tender" is comparable to the person of
"Il Principe" in the writings of Machiavelli. And the Prince (in the
Machiavellian sense) naturally has a circle of advisors and counselors (some
of whom may be qualified to be called
macro-economists
or economists).
The
advisors to the Prince will typically find it easier and more strategically
wise not to criticize the fundamental structure of the Prince’s provision, for
his Principality, of a specific medium usable to facilitate exchanges of
utility. And financial institutions, in the Principality, may have become
adapted over time periods like at least a generation or maybe of several
genera-
tions to the specific characteristics of the money
system, perhaps the “legal tender”, that is provided in the Principality.
If the
(effective) position of being the Prince is rotating or like a political office
with a “term limit” then it can easily happen that one Prince will want to
spend heavily, on his own most favored projects, before
the next Prince will come to power with his own
quite different agenda and perceived system of preferences
for state expenditures and taxation. And a current
Prince may not infrequently be able to spend additional money without
immediately raising taxes, thinking to leave
that burden to his successor and to his successor’s (legislative)
Government. (And also such a Prince can naturally think that if his successor
finds that the Treasury is relatively bare of resources and that tax income is
limited that that successor will be discouraged from heavily spending on his own
pet areas (which might
be viewed as undesirable from the viewpoint of the
current Prince).)
Thus,
viewed in this fashion, systems of economic foundations (for labor, business, and
exchanges) that have actually many areas of deficiency compared with the ideal
possibilities (which can be imagined by consideration of foundations of a more
ideal quality); these systems can yet persist over long time periods in a
manner similar to that of the persistence of political and governmental systems
that are ultimately judged to have been of an inferior or unfavorable
sort.
From 1917
to 1989 (dating to the fall of the “Berlin wall”) an economic system existed in
Europe that, arguably, failed to efficiently motivate human entrepreneurial
labor through a system of materially valuable rewards to the (entrepreneurial)
workers.(In the future Socialism may, possibly, find a good solution for the
problem of providing motivation for innovative works of practical value.)
And we
can’t really logically assume that human civil-ization has found the ultimate
ideal of forms of social government in the times of the twentieth century. (One
can imagine a future form of government where a highly advanced automaton (or
array of computers) would function like
the office of a City Manager with the human input to
the government passing through the analogue of a City Council.)
Ideal Money
Our
proposal is that a preferable version of a general system for the transferring
of utility, thus a "medium of exchange", would be structured so as to
provide a medium with a natural (and reliable!) stability of value. And this
stability of value would be particularly of benefit in connection with
contracts or exchanges involving long time periods for the complete performance
of the contract or exchange.
Classically, when gold or silver was used as the basis of a standard for
exchanges, that objective was consequen-tly achieved (even though neither of
these two "precious metals" would be, in fact, perfectly stable in
value by comparison with the other). The existence of a standard provided
comparative certainty contrasting with the gamblers’ situation that results
when a lender must lend money without much of an assurance that in 30 years the
value of it will not have been greatly eroded by inflation. Thus, faced with
such value uncertainties, mortgage lenders must learn to lend, if they are
lending their own money,
at sufficiently high interest rates so as to have a
fair chance of winning their gamble against inflation!
We
published a paper entitled "Ideal Money" in the Southern Economic
Journal (in 2002) and it was essentially the text of a keynote lecture that we
gave on that topic at the meeting of the Southern Economic Association in
Tampa, Florida. Of course, necessarily, on a topic with such
a universal relevance to human affairs, it is
difficult, really, to say something new. But there can be novelty
in the details and in terms of the context and the
times.
Our key
proposal was/is that an index that can be called an ICPI or "Industrial
Consumption Price Index" could be employed as a basis for the
standardization of
the value of money. This proposal is for an index
based
on the international prices of specific goods. For
example like the prices for silver or copper as recorded daily at London.
The
commodities or utilities or services for which their international prices could
be used in an ICPI index should be wisely chosen so as to avoid those that
might have comparatively rapidly changing prices. Exactly how
an index should be constituted cannot be specified
at this point but it can be noted that the problem of constituting a suitable
index is quite analogous to that of constituting index measures for the prices
of "Industrials" or "Trans-ports" or "Utilities"
like Dow Jones has long had for the stocks traded on the New York Stock
Exchange. But of course one doesn’t expect the value measure of a
"basket" of commodities to rise as much, over long times, as the
value of the Dow Jones Industrials index has risen in the past.
We also
observed that a method of calculation could be employed that would use
"moving averages" to achieve that the money value being defined would
vary as smoothly and gradually as practicable with the passing of time.
But now we
want to mention another possibility that arises because of the present day
circumstances that are relevant to the international interactions of the
various national currencies. It could be very difficult, and a slow process, to
set up such a practical and useful system of conventions as the international
metric system of measures (of length, volume, and weight). So it should not be
expected that reform and progress, in the area of systems of money, will be
very easily achieved.
Nowadays
we see some new areas of competition between different major currencies of the
world since the euro has come into existence and the psychological climate in
which the "central bankers" are operating is recently changed by the
theme that is next described.
The Confessional of Targeting
It was the
observation of a new "line" that has become popular with those
responsible for "central banking" functions relating to national
currencies that gave us
the idea for the theme of "asymptotically
ideal" money.
The idea
seems paradoxical, but by speaking of "inflation targeting" these
responsible officials are effectively CONFESSING that, notwithstanding how they
formerly were speaking about the difficulties and problems of their functions,
that it is indeed after all possible
to control inflation by controlling the supply of
money
(as if by limiting the amount of individual
"prints" that could be made of a work of art being produced as
"prints").
This
popularity of the line of "inflation targeting" seems to have started
in New Zealand, which is the place, among the USA, Canada, Australia, and New
Zealand, which had the most depreciated dollar. And we can note also that New
Zealand was hardly a place where any crisis of poverty really forced them to
not maintain the value of their dollar but rather just a place where
"Keynesian" thinking was probably very influential.
If now we
think of a world of a number of major currencies and with all of these provided
by central authorities that operate under some sort of a ritual of
"inflation targeting" then, as things evolve, what SHOULD the targets
be?
It is only
really respectable that there should not be an arbitrary or capricious pattern
of inflation, but how should a proper and desirable form of money value
stability be defined?
Rapid
inflation is easily measured, on a national
level, by a domestically defined "cost of
living" index.
So if the cost of living, as measured by another
agency than central banking authorities, were not rising (when expressed in
terms of the domestic money) then one could feel assured that there was not
inflation.
However
this requirement is actually a little too strong (for a properly good money
worthy to be called
of "ideal" type)! It is actually quite
natural for the calculated "cost of living" to be rising, even when
measured, say, in terms of gold, whenever there is so much technological
progress that the people in an area, without working harder, are lifted to a
higher standard of living
by the rapid progress, as if each human would become
the beneficiary of the assistance of 3 robot helpers to do
the work of his livelihood.
So in the
last years of the era of the gold standard the "cost of living"
measures were gradually rising, in “advanced countries”, but it was not
appropriate to view that as indicating inflation since the money was not losing
value in relation to alternative options for "treasure hoarding",
(such as gold!).
To be
quite respectable, in a Gresham-advised sense, money needs only to be AS GOOD
as other material commod-ities that might be hoarded. It does not really need
to be so good (as time passes) that the cost of living statistic should remain
constant.
But
"inflation targeting", unless all major currencies would (somehow!)
be able to be adopting and really employ-ing the same target rate, would still
provide the oppor-tunity for "connoisseurs of quality" to rank the
currencies in hierarchies of gradations of quality (like bond rating agencies
rank the debt of commercial enterprises or like other rating agencies
comparatively appraise various insurance companies). Those really having lower
planned inflation rates would naturally be seen as superior in quality. (We
should note that the INTERNATIONAL perspect-ive relating to a currency is not
how it relates to domes-tically measured costs in its home country but how it
compares, on the international markets, with other currencies and commodities.)
What
inflation targeting does is to open up the possib-ility that somehow the
various major currencies may evolve to develop stability of value. And in this
sense there could be "asymptotically ideal money" in that an evolving
trend could lead to the value stability that would consti-tute a major
improvement in quality.
Currencies
in Competition
It is
observable that certain types of financial enterprises, such as large
internationally operating insurance companies, tend to migrate to national
homes where the national currency is of at least comparatively higher quality
(such as, e. g., Switzerland).
In the
near future there may be a smaller number of major currencies used in the world
and these may stand in competitive relations among themselves. There is now the
"euro" and the inflationary tradition of the Italian lira seems to be
past history now. And there COULD be introd-uced, for example, a similar
international currency for
the Islamic world, or for South Asia, or for South
America,
or here or there.
And if
"inflation targeting" were used as a "line" by the managers
handling all of these various internationally prominent currencies then there
would arise interesting possibilities for comparisons between these major
curren-cies. Each of the currencies managed thusly would have
its officially recognized status in terms of
inflation as measured by the domestic index of costs of the state of
the managers. But also, and this is what is more
signif-icant from an internationally oriented viewpoint, the various currencies
would have rates of exchange so that they could be realistically compared in
terms of their actual values.
And so the
various currencies managed with "inflation targeting" would be comparable
by users or observers who would be able to form opinions about the quality of
the currencies. And what I want to suggest is that "the public" or
the users, those for whom a medium of exchange functions as a basic utility,
may develop opinions that are critical of currencies of lower "value
quality". That is, the public may learn to demand better quality of that
which CAN be managed to be of better quality or which can be managed to be of
the lower quality observed in so many of the various national currencies in the
20th century.
So we can
imagine the evolutionary possibility of “asymptotically ideal money".
Starting with the idea of value stabilization in relation to a domestic price
index associated with the territory of one state, beyond that there is the
natural and logical concept of internationally based value comparisons. The
currencies being compared, like now the euro, the dollar, the yen, the pound,
the Swiss franc, the Swedish krona, etc. can be viewed with critical eyes by
their users and by those who may have
the option of whether or not or how to use one of
them. This can lead to pressure for good quality and consequently
for a lessened rate of inflationary depreciation in
value.
Illustrating these optional choices that the public, the users of a
money, may have, the people of Sweden recently had the opportunity of voting in
a referendum
on whether or not Sweden should join the
eurocurrency bloc and replace the krona by the euro and thus use the same
currency as Finland. The people voted against that, for various reasons. But it
cannot be irrelevant whether or
not the future quality of a currency is really
assured
or whether instead that it depends on the shifting
sands
of political decisions or the possibly arbitrary
actions
of a bureaucracy of officials.
The voters
in the U.K. are expecting to have the opportunity to vote in a referendum
relating to the adoption, for the U.K., of the euro (which is already adopted
in Ireland). Here they have a dramatic conflict, since the pound was the
original currency of "the gold standard", with its value pegged to
gold in 1717 by Isaac Newton (who was then Master of the Mint).
In recent
years the pound has had a comparatively good rating with regard to inflation,
inferior to the rating
of the Swiss franc but superior to most currencies
of the world. So the British have the alternatives of accepting adoption of the
euro when first voting, or after a delay, or never.
We can
legitimately wonder how the speediness of its adoption or delays in its
adoption might affect the poli-cies operating to control the actual exchange
value of the euro. The constitutional structure of the authority behind the
euro is of the "paper money" character in that nothing is really
guaranteed as far as the value of the euro is concerned. But this is typical of
all currencies used
in the world nowadays.
Of course
when a currency, for a time, does have a specification of its value beyond that
simply depending
on supply and demand for a fiat money, like the
money of Argentina had a peg to the U.S. dollar a few years ago, then
international observers can wisely distrust the reliability of such a
stabilization of its value. Such forms of value definition are not necessarily
unsound, particularly when a small economy, like that of Panama, links its
currency to that of a larger area like that
of the USA. But it is obvious that this sort of
thing puts
a (paradoxical) burden on the foundation of the
currency that is used as a reference basis.
For example,
if all sorts of non-European countries decided to define the values of their
currencies as on a par with the euro, without actually joining into any system
of cooperative regulations associated with that, then
the effect of that would seem likely to destabilize
the stability of the euro if it would otherwise be highly stable and of good
value quality.
Insurance Companies,
Commercial Banks, and State Banks
It can be
difficult, psychologically, for good patriots to appreciate the comparison, but
state banks, or whatever issues the money used in a state or in a group of
states, are logically comparable to good or bad commercial banks
or to good or bad insurance companies.
And it is
observable that internationally operating commercial banks or insurance
companies can be favored by being based where the conventional money is of
relatively higher quality. The same principle also applies to the business of
"investment banking" which is a differentiable specialty function of
commercial banks or other financial companies.
Savings,
Savings Institutions,
and Savings Rates
Another
area where money quality is very relevant is
in relation to the "savings rate". How
will individual decision makers behave with regard to options for thrifty or more
“spendthrift" behavior? It is arguable that the larger classes, in the
sense of economically differentiated population strata, should be able to
employ thrift options that are not extremely complex in character. And if the
quality of the money is really good then simply to save
in terms of the ordinary medium of exchange is at
least a practical first step. So thus the existence of good money may naturally
promote a higher "savings rate".
The
history of "savings banks" and "credit unions" seems to
illustrate social and economic developments that occurred during the time of
stable money values of the gold standard era. Thus forms of financial
institutions came into existence in the climate of "good money" which
would not have evolved were the money of an obviously unstable value.
The
process of capital investment by means of which enterprises prepare to have the
competence for making successful products in the future naturally relates to
the processes recognizable as involving savings
decisions by individuals and households. And it can become as if paradoxical,
when the official "savings rate" is found
to be low, how the investment processes are
occurring.
The truth may be that the mass of the citizens of a
state
with an apparently advanced economy can become
actually comparable to the people of an area being developed by colonialists
and thus not be a leading force in relation
to the advancement of the national economy.
Relations to Law and Contracts
A concept
that we thought of later than at the time
of developing our first ideas about Ideal Money is
that
of the importance of the comparative quality of the
money used in an economic society to the possible precision, as an indicator of
quality, of the contracts for performances of future contractual obligations.
We have
noted, as a matter of general theory, that money provides the practical means
for the “transfer of utility” and that the distinction between “games with
transferable utility” and “games with non-transferable utility” (or TU and NTU
games) thus is naturally linked with the matter of whether or not there is
available the means of money transfers to facilitate a good cooperative game
solution (which could be that of a relatively simple game of bargaining).
But when
there is the dimension of time also, incorpor-ated into a contract for
exchanges (such as for example a mortgage contract, or an annuity contract with
an insurance company, or a contract for services to be performed over
an extended period of time) then the quality of the
money unit in terms of which the contract is written makes a big difference in
the level of certainty of the contract terms.
Uncertainty perturbing the issue of the effective meaning of a contract
is comparable to and analogous to
a climate of lawlessness that would make contracts,
in general, unreliable.
It is
reasonable to expect that were the quality of
a national currency very high (in terms of the
stability
of the value of the currency unit) then that
interest rates
on mortgages or on the national debt would become
compara-tively low (as “rational expectations” would interact with investment
options for mortgage and investment bankers).
If there
were only the alternatives of two varieties
of money of which one of them would depreciate in
value, compared with the other of them, AT A CONSTANT RATE, then it would be
reasonable to expect that REAL interest rates, say for mortgages, could be the
same whichever money were used. But the pattern to be expected when there is
money that decreases in value compared with “real value” measures is that this
continuous devaluation IS NOT AT A CONSTANT RATE (and the phenomenon of
“surprise inflation”, which
has been much discussed by economists, is to be
expected). (So of course, expected, it won’t be entirely a “surprise”, but yet,
when “Keynesian” policies are strongly in effect, one must rationally expect
inflation but also a degree of difficulty for precisely and quantitatively
predicting that inflation!)
Ideal Global Money, the Concept
It is not
a new concept in economic theory, that there could be material benefits
whenever a number of separate
currencies would be replaced by a single money. This
caught
the eye of John Stuart Mill, in particular.
But with a
benefit there may also come the reverse
of benefits and it is logical for human advisors of
human societies to be wary when the world, in 2008, seems not
yet ready for a globally effective federal government
comparable to those operating on national levels in Berne
or Washington.
My opinion
is that if it were too easy to set up a form of “global money” that the version
achieved might have characteristics of inferiority which would make it, compar-atively,
more like a relatively inferior national currency than like any of the more
praiseworthy national or imperial currencies known to historical records.
But there
is a good prospect for avoiding the establ-ishment of another, possibly
deceptive, currency of infer-ior quality. Here I think of the possibility that a
good sort of international currency might EVOLVE before the time when an
official establishment might occur.
We can
observe that, in the world, that there continue
to exist varieties of areas where religion,
language, laws,
and customs are quite variable. And one can suspect
that
indeed it is somewhat in the nature of Man and his
cultures
that this variableness is typical.
So my
personal view is that a practical global money
might most favorably evolve through the development
first of a few regional currencies of truly good quality. And then the
“integration” or “coordination” of those into
a global currency would become just a technical
problem.
(Here I am thinking of a politically neutral form of
a
technological utility rather than of a money which
might,
for example, be used to exert pressures in a
conflict
situation comparable to “the cold war”.)
A
process analogous to this occurred when a number of
European countries passed first through EFTA, then
through
the EU, then into an “exchange rates stabilization”
and then into the structure of “the euro” (which is based in Frankfurt).
Another
topic to consider is that if a few large-scale
currencies are interacting then that the agencies
(or states) responsible for each of these currencies might benefit by holding
certain amounts of currency reserves in terms of the other major currencies.
And also the authority
managing one currency might calculate an appropriate
index
to define the standard value for that currency by
using
the observed values of the other major world
currencies. (We mentioned before the use of less volatile values in connection
with “smoothing out” the calculations of a normative ICPI index that would
define a standard value
for a currency.)
At the
present time it can observed that the currency
of China has a value stabilized in relation to an
index
based on the values of other currencies. So in the
future
it could be that the currency sponsored by Japan or
by
the Southeast Asia Economic Cooperation Area might
become
stabilized in value with the aid of a index
including the
value of the currency of China.
Evolution of Customs and Opinions
In a large
state like one of the "great democracies"
it is reasonable to say that the people should be
able, in principle, to decide on the form of a money (like a "public
utility") that they should be served by, even though most of the actual
volume of the use of the money would be out of the hands of the great majority
of the people. But most typically the people would expect to be served by their
elected representatives and not to make most of the relev-ant decisions in a
direct fashion.
If it
becomes a matter of strong and definite prefer-ences that the money used should
have definite character-istics of quality then, in principle, the people can
demand that. For example formerly there was the drachma and now there is, in
Greece, the euro instead of that. And the people seem to be pleased with the
change.
So the
quality of the medium or media of exchange that is/are used can be improved, if
the improvement is really desired. Here we speak of quality in the sense of
Gresham or like a bond rating agency.
But the
famous classical "Gresham’s Law" also reveals the intrinsic
difficulty. Thus "good money" will not naturally supplant and replace
"bad money" by a simple Darwinian superiority of competitive species.
Rather than that, it must be that the good things are established by the
voluntary choice of human agencies. And these respon-sible agencies, being
naturally of the domain of politic-ally derived authorities, would need to make
appropriate efforts to achieve such a goal and to pay the costs that are
entailed before their societies can benefit. And the benefits would come from
the improvement in the quality
of this public utility (money) which serves to
facilitate the game-theoretic function of "the transfer of utility".
An example
of an efficiently working global reform (at least in relation to electronic
manufactures) is the metric system, with its central Bureau located near Paris.
There is an example of a system of yardsticks where inflation
is currently NOT in fashion.